What was industrialization in russia




















Real wages in the Soviet Union, — Review of Economics and Statistics 36, — Cheremukhin, A. The industrialization and economic development of Russia through the lens of a neoclassical growth model. Connolly, R. Troubled times: stagnation, sanctions, and the prospects for economic reform in Russia. Crisp, O. Studies in the Russian Economy before London: Macmillan. London: Routledge, — Davies, R.

The Economic Transformation of the Soviet Union, — Materials for a Balance of the Soviet National Economy, — Dennison, T. The Institutional Framework of Russian Serfdom. Living standards in nineteenth-century Russia. Dohan, M. Slavic Review 35, — Easterly, W. The Soviet economic decline. World Bank Economic Review 9, — Ellman, M. The Disintegration of the Soviet Economic System.

New York: Routledge. Entov, R. Growth trends in Russia after Ericson, R. Command economy and its legacy. Oxford: Oxford University Press, 51— Erlich, A. The Soviet Industrialization Debate, — Estrin, S. The effects of privatization and ownership in transition economies. Journal of Economic Literature 47, — Transition Report Transition in Crisis. London: EBRD. Transition Report Recovery and Reform. Fedorov, V. Moscow: Moscow University Press.

The Making of Global Finance. Gaidar, Y. Moscow: Rosspen. Russia: A Long View. Gatrell, P. The Tsarist Economy: — London: B. Batsford Ltd. Government, Industry and Rearmament in Russia, — Gerschenkron, A. The rate of growth in Russia: the rate of industrial growth in Russia, since Journal of Economic History 7, — Agrarian policies and industrialization, Russia — Cambridge: Cambridge University Press, — Gimpelson, V. Labor market adjustment: is Russia different?

Goldsmith, R. The economic growth of Tsarist Russia, — Economic Development and Cultural Change 9, — Goodrich, M. Foreign trade. Gregg, A. Factory productivity and the concession system of incorporation in late Imperial Russia. Gregory, P. Economic growth and structural change in Tsarist Russia: a case of modern economic growth?

Soviet Studies 23, — Grain marketings and peasant consumption, Russia, — Explorations in Economic History 17, — Russian National Income, — The Political Economy of Stalinism.

Journal of Economic Literature 43, — Guriev, S. The role of oligarchs in Russian capitalism. Journal of Economic Perspectives 19, — Hanson, P. Harrison, M. Trends in Soviet labor productivity, — war, postwar recovery, and slowdown. European Review of Economic History 2, — Coercion, compliance, and the collapse of the Soviet command economy.

Economic History Review 55, — Secrets, lies, and half truths: the decision to disclose Soviet defense outlays. Hill, F. Johnson, S. The macroeconomics of NEP.

Economic History Review 46, — Evolutsiia promyshlennogo proizvodstva Rossii. Moscow: Russian Academy of Sciences. Kahan, A. Government policies and the industrialization of Russia. Journal of Economic History 27, — Capital formation during the early period of industrialization in Russia, — Kessler, G.

The peasant and the town: rural—urban migration in the Soviet Union, — Khaustova, E. Pre-revolution living standards: Russia, — Kim, B. The income, savings, and monetary overhang of Soviet households. Journal of Comparative Economics 27, — Causes of repressed inflation in the Soviet consumer market, — retail price subsidies, the siphoning effect, and the budget deficit. Kontorovich, V. What did Soviet rulers maximize?

Europe—Asia Studies 61, — Kornai, J. Economics of Shortage. Amsterdam: North-Holland. Kouwenhoven, R. A comparison of Soviet and US industrial performance: — McCaffray, S. The Politics of Industrialization in Tsarist Russia. McKay, J. McKinsey Global Institute. Markevich, A.

Byla li sovetskaia ekonomika planovoi? Planirovanie v narkomatakh v e gg. In Ekonomicheskaia istoriia. Ezhegodnik Moscow: Rosspen, n. Soviet urban households and the road to universal employment, from the end of the s to the end of the s. Continuity and Change 20, — Economic development of the late Russian Empire in regional perspective.

Repression and punishment under Stalin: evidence from the Soviet archives. Journal of Economic History 71, — Economic effects of the abolition of serfdom: evidence from the Russian Empire.

Mau, V. Modernization and the Russian economy: three hundred years of catching up. Oxford: Oxford University Press, 29— Mikhailova, T. Essays on Russian economic geography: measuring spatial inefficiency.

Millar, J. Mass collectivization and the contribution of Soviet agriculture to the first five year plan: a review article. Slavic Review 33, — Blagosostoianie naselenia i revoliutsii v imperskoi Rossii.

Moscow: Novyi khronograf. Mitchell, B. International Historical Statistics: Europe, — London: Macmillan Reference. Moorsteen, R. The Soviet Capital Stock, — Homewood, IL: Richard D. Irwin, Inc. Nafziger, S. Peasant communes and factor markets in late nineteenth-century Russia. Explorations in Economic History 47, — Ofer, G. Soviet economic growth: — Journal of Economic Literature 25, — Owen, T. Popov, V. Life cycle of the centrally planned economy: why Soviet growth rates peaked in the s.

Basingstoke: Palgrave Macmillan, 35— Rumer, B. Investment and Reindustrialization in the Soviet Economy. Boulder, CO: Westview Press. Sah, R. The economics of price scissors. American Economic Review 74, — Sanchez-Sibony, O. Depression Stalinism: the Great Break reconsidered. Explorations in Russian History 15, 23— Schoors, K. Russian banking as an active volcano. Shpotov, B. Moscow: Rosspen, — Shwartz, S.

Labor in the Soviet Union. New York: Frederick A. Smirnov, S. Opyt rekonstruktsii, — gody. Voprosy ekonomiki 6, 59— Krizisy i tsikly, — gody. Voprosy ekonomiki 7, — Sokolov, A. Perspektivi izucheniia rabochei istorii v sovremennoi Rossii. Otechestvennaia istoriia 4—5, —9. Strumilin, S. Dinamika oplaty promyshlennogo truda v Rossii za — gg. Planovoe khoziaistvo 9, — Oplata truda v Rossii. Planovoe khoziaistvo 7—8, — Suhara, M. An estimation of Russian industrial production: — Russian industrial growth: an estimation of a production index, — Tarr, D.

Russian trade and foreign direct investment policy at the crossroads. Timmer, M. Is mining fueling long-run growth in Russia? Industry productivity growth trends since Review of Income and Wealth 60, S—S Tomoff, K. Russian History 22, — Sergei Witte and the Industrialization of Russia. New York: Columbia University Press.

Weitzman, M. Soviet postwar growth and capital-labor substitutability. American Economic Review 60, — World Development Indicators Online. Washington, DC: World Bank. Zalesky, E. Stalinist Planning for Economic Growth, — For example, Crisp , p.

According to one estimate, Poland produced about 8 per cent of Imperial output in , and per capita income was about 5 roubles more than the mean of roughly 74 roubles Markevich, a.

Our industrial output series includes Poland for the Imperial period, which was more industrialized than Russia 23 against 14 roubles per capita in , but we are confident that our interpretations would hold if we were able to exclude that region. In the Moscow region, peasant households allocated much of their labour to proto-industrial activities in putting-out systems for weaving cloth, along with artisanal production of crafts and small-scale artisanal goods.

Limited quantitative evidence suggests that the number of factories and the factory labour force increased steadily over the first sixty years of the nineteenth century, albeit from extremely low levels. On Russian industrial growth before , see Blackwell and Kahan ; The installation of relatively high revenue tariffs on manufacturing goods from created some protection for domestic production, which persisted throughout the Tsarist era Blackwell, , Chapter 5.

Overall, the legal environment for large-scale industrial firms remained relatively weak in the Tsarist period Owen, Incorporation was expensive and politicized, although firms that did receive a formal charter were able to tap domestic and foreign capital markets and expand as a result Gregg, We do not think that excluding mining or fuels would significantly change the overall patterns.

Another component of state intervention in this period was a conservative macroeconomic policy environment geared towards establishing convertibility with gold—an achievement reached in For more revisionist work on rural living standards, see Dennison and Nafziger and Mironov At the same time, securities markets were often quite thin, and many firms probably faced credit constraints Gregg, Russian rates were comparable to those in land-rich and capital-scarce Argentina and Brazil in this period.

Although they provide little evidence on this, Cheremukhin et al. The extent of such arrangements remains unknown, and the literature asserts that tariffs were typically applied quite indiscriminately and that foreign capital inflows were increasingly in the form of portfolio investment over the period. Soviet policies also encouraged females to actively enter the labour force.

More than 40 per cent of employees in large industry establishments were women by Davies et al. Despite the decrease in industrial wages, average living standards exceeded pre levels by the late s, because of the reallocation of labour between sectors and an increase in employment Allen, Spatial data are also suggestive.

Using modern Canada and Imperial Russia as benchmarks, Mikhailova estimates that the population in Siberia and the Far East would have been 35 per cent less in if development had been entirely market driven.

The growth of Soviet GDP, total factor productivity, and factor inputs, — Note : The source is Ofer Our GDP per capita growth rates in Table 3. All numbers are average percentage growth rates over the period in question. The Cold War sharply curtailed technological imports. The experience of industry in other former Soviet Republics was roughly similar Aslund, a.

However, the rising importance of oil and natural gas rents is also evident in Fig. While the quantity of Russian natural gas exports rose over the period, other sources were coming online, and Russian production costs remained quite high, thereby reducing rents.

Obsolete technologies and capital vintages, coupled with deteriorating labour market conditions, generated extremely low factor utilization rates and industrial productivity that persisted well after McKinsey Global Institute, Moreover, the legacies of the geographic misallocation of Soviet industrial activity further raised the costs of inputs, labour, and transportation Hill and Gaddy, On the other hand, the poor institutional environment for businesses has constrained firm entry and reinforced concentration, especially in connection to a rebound in state ownership and control in resource-related sectors.

Imports and exports rose sharply, with the net trade balance positive and constituting between 8 and 20 per cent of GDP from onwards Table 3. Thus, the story of industrial decline—in manufacturing as well as mining—in the s is much more about the decline in capital and labour services than about technological factors.

However, recent political constraints on trade have possibly fostered conditions for some growth in domestic manufacturing Connolly, In general, recent Putin policies may be mimicking import-substitution industrialization policies often associated with Latin American stagnation Tarr and Volchkova, All Rights Reserved. OSO version 0. University Press Scholarship Online. Sign in. Not registered? Sign up. Publications Pages Publications Pages. Recently viewed 0 Save Search.

The Spread of Modern Industry to the Periphery since Find in Worldcat. Go to page:. Your current browser may not support copying via this button. Search within book. Subscriber sign in You could not be signed in, please check and try again. Username Please enter your Username.

Password Please enter your Password. Forgot password? You could not be signed in, please check and try again. Sign in with your library card Please enter your library card number. Value added by sector in the Imperial Russian economy, and Total millions of roubles Per cent Total millions of roubles Per cent Agriculture 5, Russian day wages and yearly salaries, — Note : All data are taken from Strumilin ; Russian macroeconomic indicators, select years Household final consumption expenditure, etc.

Sectoral value-added shares and resource rents, — Note : These data are taken from the WDI References Bibliography references: Acemoglu, D. Petersburg and Moscow. These lines were financed primarily with foreign capital and as the domestic iron industry was unable to meet the demand for rails, locomotives and wagons, these had to be imported.

Alexander II finally eliminated serfdom in , but this did not result in economic growth because the peasants remained dependent on the noble landowners, and in the mines of the Urals, which were worked by serfs, iron production even declined.

However, the expanding rail network helped to significantly increase grain exports via the ports of the Baltic and Black Seas. The government now began to channel funding into heavy industry, production of hard coal increased, as did iron and steel production, and towards the end of the 19th century the Russian Empire experienced the first phase of industrialisation.

In this initial period of growth, the government succeeded in stabilising the rouble with the aid of import tariffs and by attracting foreign investment. Construction of the Trans-Siberian Railway commenced in — primarily for strategic reasons — and was completed in Petersburg developed into a centre for machinery manufacturing, while the textile industry in particular flourished in Moscow.

Yet outside of these two rapidly growing metropolises, Russia was still an agrarian country when the Bolsheviks seized power in Steelmaking and coal mining — in the formerly soviet Ukraine and in Siberia — quadrupled. New power stations delivered electricity, new canals and railways facilitated transportation, and the economic development of Siberia continued to advance.

However, this rapid advancement through the ranks of the great industrial nations came at the price of flagrant neglect of agriculture, dramatic shortages of consumer goods, and the constant fear of the ruthless power of the state. Motovolikha Copper Mill.



0コメント

  • 1000 / 1000